Other formats

    Adobe Portable Document Format file (facsimile images)   TEI XML file   ePub eBook file  

Connect

    mail icontwitter iconBlogspot iconrss icon

The Pamphlet Collection of Sir Robert Stout: Volume 68

Net Produce of Rural Industries

Net Produce of Rural Industries.

New Zealand. Victoria.
Gross agricultural produce £3,405,000 £7,260,735
Lew one-quarter of the oats, half the hay, and all green forage and "other root crops" 808,849 1,852,166page 16
Net agricultural produce £2,596,000 £5,408,569
Pastoral produce 7,149,000 8,911,336
Total net produce £9,745,000 £14,319,905
Persons engaged in agriculture and pasturage 65,178 136,976
Produce per head £149 £101
Produce excluded from comparison £821,000

Mining.

The most important facts in respect of this industry are the stationary condition of the production of gold and the very rapid growth of the production of coal With respect to the former, it remains to be sea whether the investments of foreign capital in quartz reefs will result in again raising the exports of gold; but so far as coal is concerned, the increase in the years between the last census and the one preceding it may be really called extraordinary, the amounts raised being 277,918 tons in 1880 and 481,858 in 1885.

As there was no mining of any importance in Victoria except gold mining, I have compared the average earnings of all miners in New Zealand with those U gold miners in Victoria. The result is distinctly fa favour of Victoria, but it is impossible to be sure of the number of men really engaged in the industry in either colony. The numbers given for Victoria are the estimates of the Victorian Department of Mines, while our census returns probably include a number of men who are only working a part of their time at mining. The reason for this opinion is that in the mines of which we have particular returns—that is practically, all the mines worthy of the name that are in operation—the average product is £252 per head far gold mining, and £211 per head for all mines and quarries; and if we exclude both the hands and the products thus accounted for, we get an average of only £48 a head for the remaining miners. Thus in this case the comparison is unsatisfactory, but the value of total products is probably not far wrong, depending, as it does, on the export returns in the case of gold, and special returns from managers of mines and quarries for the other items. Kauri gum digging cannot be in eluded among mining industries without spoiling the average, because the return per head appears to be much larger than is really the case. The only diggers who are enumerated in the census are Europeans, but page 17 it is known the large quantities of gum are the produce of Maoris, which accounts for the fact that the produce per head appears to be abnormally high.

Value of Mining Produce, 1885.
New Zealand. Victoria.
Value of total produce £1,164,599 £3,091,244
Number of miners 12,643
Average value of produce per head £92 £108*
Excluded from comparison-Kauri gum, exports 1885 £299,762

Manufactories.

In both New Zealand and Victoria very elaborate returns of manufactures are obtained, and if we can trust the figures we may get a very accurate idea of our Relative positions. The commonest objection to the comparison is that we include numbers of small establishments which would be excluded in Victoria. All the information that I could obtain from the Registrar-General's department went to show that this is not the case; that the class of establishments is the fame as in Victoria. The comparison, however, made out such a good case for the manufactures of the colony that I could hardly believe it to be correct; so I tested the returns in various ways, examining the nature of the industries, the number of hands in particular works, and the horse power employed. The result was that I concluded the comparison is a perfectly fair one, and the best illustration of this is the amount of power employed in comparison with the number of the establishments. We employ 19,315 horse-power in our 2268 establishments, while Victoria employes 20,160 horse-power in 2813; so that relatively our power is the greater. The comparison, however, is not quite fair until we exclude mines, which are put on a separate table by the Victorian statist; if we do this we reduce the horse power to 15,615 and the establishments to 1961, which gives an average of just under eight horse power to each establishment, against just over seven horse-power in Victoria; even this is not quite conclusive, because some of our power is manual, &c., whereas only engine power is reckoned in Victoria, so I will compare the number of establish- page 18 ments using engines. In Victoria there were in 1886 1409, and in New Zealand 815 using steam, 281 using water, 66 using gas, and 44 using other motive powers If we compare the number of hands per establishment we find 11 hands in New Zealand against 17 in Victoria which, allowing for the very large works in Victoria seems to show that the comparison is fair. With our widely separated centres of industry we have naturally smaller works and more of them. If mere shops where some industry is carried on had been included, our average number of workers to each establishment would be far smaller than this. Another reason for believing that our returns represent real industries aided by machinery, is the high average produce per head, and yet another is that thinking over particular branches of production, such as dyesinking, I find they are considered too small to be taken into account although we know that they exist in numbers which must make the total produce worth consideration.

For these reasons, the comparison seems to me to be fair, and accordingly I show the results in the subjoined table. If you compare it with the statistics you will find that I put down our total production at a smaller amount than is given in them; the reasons is that I have excluded mines because they are not included in the Victorian tables. The value of raw material is generally given in the returns of bolt, colonies; but our returns appear to be less perfect and in the case of "animal matters" and sawmilling I have had to estimate the value, which I did by taking the same proportion as obtains in similar industries in Victoria and adding over £70,000 to the total to represent the probable excess in the value of our raw material in animal matters. In any case the value of raw materials given can only be regarded as roughly approximate. The value of the net produce in New Zealand is very high, but on account of the uncertainty about the value of raw material I cannot regard it as anything like exact. It will be seen, however, from a later table that it agrees fairly well with average production in other industries. The value of gross produce is certainly too low, for several factories sent in no returns of their production (nor of their raw materials), and there is reason to believe that the returns that were sent in seriously understated tat value of produce in some cases. The number of hands appears to be correct.

page 19
Produce of Manufactures.
New Zealand. Victoria.
1885. 1880-81.
Total value £6,713,000 £13,370,000
Deduct value of materials 2,980,000 7,997,000
£3,733,000 £5,373,000
Hands employed 22,102 38,141
Produce per head £168 £140

* Gold only. Mr Hayter's estimate.